HOM 1 | History of Money Course Notes (Prof. Barth, ASU)

By

AI Video Summarizer

on

August 12, 2024

The following is an AI-generated summary of Professor Barth’s History of Money course (HOM 1) available on Youtube.

Key Takeaways

  • The Evolution of Money: The course traces the development of money from ancient commodities like gold and silver to modern fiat currencies, emphasizing its central role in shaping economies and societies.
  • Types of Money: Money has evolved from commodity-based forms with intrinsic value to representative money backed by commodities, and finally to fiat money, which derives value from government decree.
  • Theories of Money's Origin: Theories explaining the origin of money include Market Theory (emerging from barter), State Theory (government creation), and Social Theory (evolving from customs).
  • Gold and Silver as Money: Gold and silver became dominant due to their intrinsic value, durability, divisibility, and portability, making them ideal forms of money for thousands of years.
  • The Price System: Prices, driven by supply and demand, serve as crucial signals that coordinate economic activities, ensuring efficient resource allocation in a market economy.
  • Inflation and Deflation: Inflation decreases the value of money and encourages spending, while deflation increases money's value and promotes saving, each impacting the economy in significant ways.

What is Money?

To understand the evolution of money, we must first address a foundational question: What is money? Despite its ubiquitous presence, most people struggle to define it precisely. While we think about money constantly, few of us stop to consider its essence. Money is often taken for granted—not just the amount we possess but the concept itself.

Money is assumed to be reliable and functional, trusted to facilitate future transactions, and viewed as something earned through hard work. Money is arguably the most important economic technology ever developed alongside its corollary- the price system.

Economic Definitions of Money

From an economic perspective, money is typically defined as a commonly accepted medium of exchange, an instrument used to trade for goods and services that fulfill needs and desires. Money also serves as a universal measure of value, with goods, services, and labor all being assigned a price in terms of money. Additionally, money functions as a store of value, allowing individuals to save and defer consumption to satisfy future needs. Unlike bartering, where goods must be exchanged immediately, money enables the accumulation of value for later use.

Broader Perspectives on Money

The concept of money extends beyond narrow economic definitions. Consider the metaphor that likens the market to an engine and money to the oil that lubricates it. Markets are essential for any prosperous economy, and money is the lubricant that ensures their smooth operation.

Beyond its economic functions, money represents power—specifically, power over goods and services. Those with more money generally wield greater influence than those with less. Karl Marx called money the "god of commodities," while sociologist Max Weber called it the "father of private property." The Bible famously describes money as the root of all evil. These metaphors underscore money's unique role in human affairs.

Money is an irresistible force; it creates and destroys relationships. It makes the world go round, and even time is often equated with money. In the modern era, data is increasingly viewed as a new form of currency.

Money is both ancient and modern. Its origins trace back thousands of years, yet it is also central to the contemporary world. Much of modern life has been monetized, with money penetrating nearly all spheres of exchange. While this has brought material benefits, it has also contributed to corruption and social inequality.

Money in Society and Politics

Historically, the study of money has been the domain of economics, often shrouded in specialized jargon and advanced mathematics. However, money can be understood on a broader level, revealing much about society and politics. The state of a monetary system reflects the strength or weakness of a nation, its victories or defeats in war, its revolutions, class structure, and even its cultural and moral life. By examining the history of money, we can gain insights into the broader dynamics of society, economy, and government.

The Origins of Commodity Money

In this session, we will explore the origins of commodity money, why gold and silver became dominant forms of currency, and examine the price system. Before venturing into the ancient world, we’ll also touch on some basic monetary theory.

Types of Money

Money can be categorized into three basic types:

  1. Commodity Money: This type of money has intrinsic value, meaning that the item or good used as money holds value independently of its role as a medium of exchange.
  2. Representative Money: This refers to items like paper notes or banknotes that have no intrinsic value but represent something that does, such as gold or silver.
  3. Fiat Money: This type of money has value because it is established by government decree. While it lacks intrinsic value, it possesses extrinsic value imposed by a governing authority.

Today, our focus will be on commodity money and its origins.

Theories on the Origins of Commodity Money

The origins of commodity money are not definitively known, as there is no direct historical record of its emergence. Instead, theories about its origins rely on logical inference and conjecture. There are three main theories regarding the origins of commodity money:

  1. Market Theory (or Barter Theory): This theory posits that money emerged spontaneously through market-based processes, developing as a solution to the inherent inefficiencies of barter.
  2. State Theory: This theory suggests that money originated through government action, where the state played a central role in the creation of money, often through laws or decrees that imposed the use of certain commodities as money.
  3. Social Theory (or Customs Theory): This theory proposes that money evolved from deeply rooted social customs, such as bride money, blood money, or restitution payments, involving specific commodities in various social exchanges.

While each theory offers valuable insights, the market theory is particularly compelling because it clearly explains why certain commodities, such as gold and silver, became money. However, the true origin of money is likely a combination of market dynamics and social customs.

The Role of Trade and Exchange in the Emergence of Money

Trade, or exchange, is essential for any economic system with a division of labor. In a society where individuals specialize in specific trades or skills, they must rely on others for goods and services they cannot produce themselves, creating a need for exchange.

In a world without money, exchange occurs through barter or direct exchange. However, barter is often inefficient due to the difficulty of finding a mutual coincidence of wants.

Indirect Exchange and the Emergence of Commodity Money

To overcome the limitations of barter, people began to use indirect exchange. For example, during World War II, soldiers received rations of cigarettes. Even non-smokers kept their cigarettes because they quickly realized that cigarettes were highly marketable. Over time, cigarettes emerged as a form of commodity money in some barracks.

Similar examples exist throughout history. The Aztecs used cacao beans as commodity money, and in early colonial America, corn, tobacco, and other goods served this role. In ancient Egypt, grain was often used as money, and in medieval Japan, iron implements like knives and spades functioned as currency.

As people recognized the marketability of certain goods, these goods became more widely accepted as mediums of exchange. When a medium of exchange becomes commonly accepted, it transitions from being just another medium of exchange to being recognized as money.

The Role of Money in Economic Specialization

Once money emerges, it becomes the ultimate good in an economy—the most coveted item within a trading community. The value of all other goods, known as their price, is calculated in terms of this money. The emergence of money facilitates a higher degree of specialization and a more complex division of labor, as it requires only a single coincidence of wants: the demander of a commodity encounters a supplier, and money is used as the medium of exchange.

This single coincidence of wants, enabled by money, significantly reduces the inefficiencies of barter, allowing for a more efficient and dynamic economy.

The Role of Gold and Silver in the History of Money

Theories on the origins of money abound, from market-based theories to state-driven and social customs theories. Regardless of which theory one subscribes to—whether it's the market theory, state theory, social theory, or a combination—the question remains: why did gold and silver emerge as the dominant forms of money? This is a critical question in any study of monetary history, given that gold and silver have been used as money for at least 5,000 years.

Intrinsic Value of Gold and Silver

For an item to function effectively as commodity money, it must possess intrinsic value—value that exists independently of its use as money. Gold and silver have been valued for their beauty and brightness for thousands of years across multiple continents. This valuation seems to transcend cultural boundaries, as seen in the Aztecs of Mesoamerica, who used gold and silver for ornamentation long before contact with Old World civilizations.

The widespread and independent appreciation of gold and silver suggests that these metals are objectively valuable. Their intrinsic value comes from their use in creating rings, ornaments, cups, and other items. However, intrinsic value alone isn't enough to explain why gold and silver became the preferred forms of money. Other properties play a crucial role.

Divisibility and Fusibility of Precious Metals

A good commodity, money must be divisible and fusible. Divisibility refers to breaking down larger units into smaller ones without losing value. Fusibility refers to combining smaller units into larger ones without compromising value. Gold and silver excel in both these aspects.

In contrast, other forms of commodity money, such as cattle or oxen, do not share these properties. For instance, in ancient Greece, oxen were sometimes used as a medium of exchange. However, they are neither easily divisible nor fusible, making them impractical as money. If the price of an item like armor had to be halved, it would be impossible to provide "half an oxen" as payment. Moreover, cattle and oxen lack portability, another essential quality of effective money.

Durability: The Longevity of Gold and Silver

Durability is another key attribute of good commodity money. Effective money must not disintegrate or lose value over time. Gold and silver are incredibly durable; they can last thousands of years without degrading. For example, ancient Roman coins have been found in remarkably good condition after more than two millennia. Even coins recovered from shipwrecks after centuries underwater remain well-preserved.

Gold and silver are not the only durable forms of commodity money. Cowrie shells, used in Southeast Asia, parts of Africa, and among some Native American tribes, were also highly durable and used as money well into the 19th century. However, cowrie shells were not divisible or fusible, which limited their utility compared to gold and silver.

Portability: Ease of Transport and Use

Portability is crucial for money, as it must be easy to transport relative to its value. Gold and silver, with their high value-to-size ratio, are highly portable. This contrasts with less portable forms of money, such as copper or bronze currency. In ancient Rome, for instance, bronze currency was cumbersome, with the main unit weighing a full pound. In Sweden, copper coins weighed as much as 43 pounds. Given the choice between bulky copper or bronze and more portable silver or gold, societies naturally gravitated toward the latter.

Scarcity: Maintaining Value Through Limited Supply

Portability implies a certain degree of scarcity. While scarcity is often seen as a negative trait, it is essential for commodity money. If gold or silver were suddenly abundant in every household, their value would plummet, undermining their utility as money. Historically, currencies like tobacco in colonial Virginia or copper in Sweden faced challenges due to their lack of scarcity, which limited their effectiveness as money.

Fungibility and Homogeneity: Interchangeability of Gold and Silver

Good commodity money must also be fungible, meaning that one unit is interchangeable with another of the same kind. An ounce of silver, for example, should be equal to any other ounce of silver in terms of quality and value. This consistency makes using silver (or gold) as money easier.

Contrast this with tobacco, which was used as money in early America. Tobacco varied in quality, with some grades being much more valuable than others. This lack of fungibility made using tobacco as an effective form of money difficult.

Imprintability: The Ability to Certify and Standardize

Imprintability refers to the ability to stamp a commodity with an official mark certifying its weight and purity. This is a key property of metals like gold and silver, which can be stamped with an official seal, making them easier to trade and reducing the need to constantly verify their authenticity.

Geographical Distribution: Global Presence of Precious Metals

For a commodity to serve as a global currency, it should be geographically well-distributed. Gold and silver fit this criterion, as they are found on every continent. However, this geographical distribution does not necessarily favor regions with abundant gold or silver mines. Mining these metals requires immense time, labor, and capital, often leading those regions to rely on imports for other necessities.

Countries without significant gold or silver mines, like Britain, often became major financial centers by trading manufactured goods for precious metals. This trade allowed them to accumulate gold and silver without the heavy investment in mining.

Conclusion: The Unique Suitability of Gold and Silver as Money

Gold and silver possess a unique combination of attributes—intrinsic value, divisibility, durability, portability, scarcity, fungibility, imprintability, and global distribution—that make them ideal as commodity money. While not all societies may choose to use commodity money, gold and silver have historically been the best options for those that do. These qualities explain why gold and silver were used as money for thousands of years and why they continue to be valued today.

Understanding these properties not only illuminates the historical use of gold and silver as money but also provides insight into the broader economic and social factors that drive the selection of a commodity as a medium of exchange. As we continue this course, we will explore the evolution of money and the shift away from commodity money in favor of modern fiat currencies.

The Price System and Its Role in the Economy

For the final section of our first lecture, we'll examine the price system—an essential component of any functioning economy. The price system is the mechanism by which goods and services are valued in terms of money. While prices result from human action—specifically, the actions of millions of individuals—they are not the product of human design. Rather, as the Austrian economist Friedrich Hayek described, prices are part of a spontaneous order that emerges naturally from countless economic transactions, influenced by the forces of supply and demand.

Hayek famously argued that if prices had been consciously invented by a single person or institution, they would be considered one of the greatest, if not the greatest, inventions in human history. That's how critical prices are to the functioning of our economy. Yet, we often take prices for granted, especially the free movement of prices, which is fundamental to coordinating economic activity.

The Function of Prices: Signals and Coordination

Prices serve as signals that coordinate economic activity. Vital information is conveyed to both consumers and producers through price signals, often without us even realizing it. For instance, in a market economy, the price of a scarce good tends to rise. This increase in price sends a signal to potential producers that producing this good is profitable, prompting them to increase their supply. As more of the good enters the market, its price stabilizes or decreases.

Conversely, when a good or service is in oversupply, its price drops, making it less attractive to produce. This self-regulating mechanism helps balance supply and demand across the economy, ensuring that resources are allocated efficiently.

Price Signals and Supply and Demand: An Example

Consider the basic supply and demand curve. If demand for a particular good suddenly increases, the demand curve shifts to the right, leading to a higher price. This price increase signals suppliers that it is more profitable to produce this good, prompting an increase in supply. The supply curve then shifts to the right, leading to a new equilibrium price.

However, the market doesn't always adjust perfectly. Due to various factors, prices can remain high or low for extended periods, but the fundamental concept of price signals remains crucial for understanding how markets function.

Case Study: The Rise and Fall of the Microsoft Zune

Let's look at a concrete example: the Microsoft Zune. Released in 2006 as a competitor to the Apple iPod, the Zune entered the market with significant fanfare and a price tag of around $200 to $300. However, consumer feedback quickly revealed that the Zune was not a particularly great product. Demand dropped, and the price of the Zune plummeted, eventually being sold for as little as $80 during sales. By 2011, Microsoft had discontinued the Zune altogether.

This decline was driven by price signals. As demand decreased, the price fell, communicating to Microsoft and consumers alike that the product was not valued in the market. Ultimately, the Zune was priced out of the market, illustrating how price signals can lead to the rise and fall of products.

The Economic Calculation Problem: Challenges Without Prices

Without prices, we encounter what Hayek called the "economic calculation problem." Without freely moving prices, it becomes nearly impossible to determine the appropriate supply and demand for goods and services. Prices are crucial for conveying knowledge between economic actors. When prices are distorted or centrally controlled, this knowledge transfer breaks down, leading to inefficient resource allocation.

The Impact of Price Controls: Distortions in the Market

Centralized attempts to control prices often lead to market distortions. For example, if a government sets a excessively high minimum wage—say, $40 per hour—the labor supply would surge as more people would be willing to work at that wage. However, the demand for labor from employers would plummet, leading to unemployment. This imbalance illustrates how price controls can create economic inefficiencies.

On the other hand, if a central authority decides that the price of a gallon of milk should be capped at $1, this would lead to a sharp increase in demand. However, at such a low price, suppliers would be unwilling or unable to produce enough milk to meet that demand, resulting in shortages. These examples demonstrate how interfering with the natural price system can lead to unintended and often harmful consequences.

Criticisms of the Price System: Limited Individual Influence

One criticism of the price system is that in a large, complex economy, the impact of any single buyer or seller on determining prices is minimal. As the market expands, individual influence on prices dilutes, leading some to argue that individuals have little say. Despite this criticism, the price system remains essential for a functioning economy.

The Price of Credit: Understanding Interest Rates

One particularly important price in the economy is the price of credit, commonly known as the interest rate. The interest rate represents the cost of borrowing money and is crucial for consumers and businesses. Credit, which involves the granting of loans and the creation of debt, is a method of deferred payment, essential for large projects and significant expenditures like college tuition.

The interest rate operates on a supply and demand basis. When the interest rate is high, it signals that credit is in high demand, making it more costly to borrow money. This high rate encourages people with money to lend it out, increasing the supply of loanable funds and eventually driving the interest rate down. Conversely, when the interest rate is low, it discourages saving and lending, which can lead to an increase in the interest rate over time.

In the United States, however, interest rates are not solely determined by the free market. The Federal Reserve plays a significant role in setting interest rates, which can lead to market distortions. For instance, in the 2000s, artificially low interest rates contributed to the housing bubble, demonstrating how central bank policies can impact the economy.

Inflation and Deflation: The Impact on Money's Value

Finally, let's define two critical concepts related to prices: inflation and deflation.

  • Inflation: Inflation occurs when the value of money falls, meaning that each unit of currency buys fewer goods and services over time. This situation often leads to increased spending, as people want to use their money before it loses value. Inflation can benefit debtors, who repay their loans with money worth less than when they borrowed it, but it harms creditors.
  • Deflation: Deflation is the opposite, where the value of money rises, increasing its purchasing power. In a deflationary environment, people are more likely to save money, anticipating it will be worth more. However, severe deflation can lead to reduced spending, causing economic stagnation. Deflation benefits creditors, as the money repaid to them is worth more than when it was lent out, but it harms debtors.

Understanding these concepts is crucial for grasping how the price system operates and influences broader economic conditions. As we continue this course, we will explore how these forces shape economic history and policy.

Back To TopSkip To End